|
Perfect information in economics is used to describe a subset of perfect competition. With perfect information in a market, all consumers and producers are assumed to have perfect knowledge of price, utility, quality and production methods of products, when theorizing the systems of free markets, and effects of financial policies. Perfect information is also a game situation in which an agent is theorized to have all relevant information with which to make a decision. It has implications for several fields. ==Game theory== In game theory, an extensive-form game has perfect information if each player, when making any decision, is perfectly informed of all the events that have previously occurred. 〔 〕 Chess is an example of a game with perfect information as each player can see all of the pieces on the board at all times. Other examples of perfect games include Tic-tac-toe, Irensei, and Go. The formal definition can be easily extended to include games with exogenous uncertainty from chance events, such as in Backgammon, or simultaneous move games, such as in the iterated prisoners' dilemma, or both, such as in Goofspiel. Card games where each player's cards are hidden from other players, as in contract bridge, are examples of games with imperfect information. In 2015 two-handed Texas hold'em with bounded bidding was solved.〔''Nature'', January 2015〕 〔 〕〔 〕 抄文引用元・出典: フリー百科事典『 ウィキペディア(Wikipedia)』 ■ウィキペディアで「Perfect information」の詳細全文を読む スポンサード リンク
|